Prices of other Commodities:
There are three types of commodities in this
context.
Substitutes:
If a rise (or fall) in the price of one
commodity leads to an increase (or decline) in the demand for another
commodity, the two commodities are said to be substitutes. In other words,
substitutes are those commodities that satisfy similar wants, such as tea and
coffee.
If the price of coffee falls, the demand for
coffee rises which brings a fall in the demand for tea because the consumers of
tea shift their demand to coffee which has become cheaper. On the other hand,
if the price of coffee rises, its demand will fall. But the demand for tea will
rise because the consumers of coffee will shift their demand to tea.
Complementary Commodities:
Where the demand for two commodities is linked
to each other, such as cars and petrol, bread and butter, tea and sugar, etc.,
they are said to be complementary goods. Complementary goods are those which
cannot be used without each other. If, say, the price of cars rises and they
become expensive, the demand for them will fall and so will the demand for
petrol. On the contrary, if the price of cars falls and they become cheaper,
the demand for them will increase and so will the demand for petrol.
Unrelated Goods:
If the two commodities are unrelated, say
refrigerator and bicycle, a change in the price of one will have no effect on
the quantity demanded of the other.
3. Income:
A rise in the consumer’s
income raises the demand for a commodity, and a fall in his income reduces the
demand for it.
4.
Tastes:
When there is a change in the
tastes of consumers in favor of a commodity, say due to fashion, its demand
will rise, with no change in its price, in the prices of other commodities, and
in the income of the consumer. On the other hand, a change in tastes against a
commodity leads to a fall in its demand, while other factors affecting demand
remain unchanged.
An Individuals Demand Schedule
and Curve:
An individual consumer’s
demand refers to the quantities of a commodity demanded by him at various
prices, other things remaining equal (y, pr, and t). An individual’s demand for
commodity “is shown on the demand schedule and on the demand curve. A demand
schedule is a list of prices and quantities and its graphic representation is a
demand curve.
Table 10.1: Demand Schedule:
Price (Rs.) |
Quantity (units) |
6 |
10 |
5 |
20 |
4 |
30 |
3 |
40 |
2 |
60 |
1 |
80 |
The
demand schedule reveals that when the price is Rs. 6, the quantity demanded is
10 units. If the price happens to be Rs 5, the quantity demanded is 20 units,
and so on. In Figure 10.1, DD1 is the
demand curve drawn on the basis of the above demand schedule. The dotted points
D, P, Q, R, S, T, and U show the various price-quantity combinations.
Marshall
calls them “demand points”. The first combination is represented by the first
dot and the remaining price- quantity combinations move to the right toward D1.
The Market Demand Schedule and
Curve:
In a market, there is not one
consumer but many consumers of a commodity. The market demand of a commodity is
depicted on a demanding schedule and a demand curve. They show the sum total of
various quantities demanded by all the individuals at various prices.
Suppose there are three
individuals A, В, and С in a market who purchase the commodity. The demand
schedule for the commodity is depicted in Table 10.2.
The last column (5) of the
Table represents the market demand for the commodity at various prices. It is
arrived at by adding columns (2), (3), and (4) representing the demand of
consumers A, В, and С respectively. The relation between columns (1) and (5)
shows the market demand schedule. When the price is very high Rs. 6 per kg. the
market demand for the commodity is 70 kgs. As the price falls, the demand
increases. When the price is the lowest Re. 1 per kg., the market demand per
week is 360 kgs.
TABLE 10.2: MARKET DEMAND SCHEDULE:
Price per kg. (Rs.) (1) |
A (2) |
Quantity Demanded in kgs. В +
(3) + |
С (4) |
Total Demand (5) |
6 |
10 |
20 |
40 |
70 |
5 |
20 |
40 |
60 |
120 |
4 |
30 |
60 |
80 |
170 |
3 |
40 |
80 |
100 |
220 |
2 |
60 |
100 |
120 |
280 |
1 |
80 |
120 |
160 |
360 |
From
Table 10.2 we draw the market demand curve in Figure 10.2. DM is the market demand curve which is the
horizontal summation of all the individual demand curves DA + DB + DC. The market demand for a commodity depends on all
factors that determine an individual’s demand.
But a better way of drawing a
market demand curve is to add together sideways (lateral summation) of all the
individual demand curves. In this case, the different quantities demanded by
consumers at one price are represented on each individual demand curve and then
a lateral summation is done, as shown in Figure 10.3.
Suppose
there are three individuals A, В, and С in a market who buy OA, OB, and ОС
quantities of the commodity at the price OP, as shown in Panels (A), (В), and
(C) respectively in Figurel0.3. In the market, OQ quantity will be bought which
is made up by adding together the quantities OA, OB, and ОС. The market demand
curve, DM is obtained by the lateral summation of the
individual demand curves DA, DB, and Dcin panel (D).
Changes in Demand:
An
individual’s demand curve is drawn on the assumption that factors such as
prices of other commodities, income, and tastes influencing his demand remain
constant. What happens to an individual’s demand curve if there is a change in
any one of the factors affecting his demand, the other factors remaining
constant? When any one of the factors changes, the entire demand curve shifts.
When an individual’s money income rises, other factors remain constant, and his
demand curve for a commodity will shift upwards to the right. He will buy more
of the commodity at a given price, as shown in Figure 10.4. Before the rise in
his income, the consumer is buying OQ1 quantity at
OP price on the D1D1 demand
curve.
With
the increase in income, his demand curve D1D1 shifts to the right as D2D2. He now buys
more quantity OQ2 at the same price as OP. When
the consumer buys more of the commodity at a given price, this is called the
increase in demand. On the contrary, if his income falls, his demand curve will
shift to the left. He will buy less of the commodity at the same price, as
shown in Figure 10.5. Before the fall in his income, the consumer is on the
demand curve D1D1where he is
buying OQ1 of the commodity at OP Price. He now buys less
quantity OP price at the given price OP. When the consumer buys less of the
commodity at a given price, this is called a decrease in demand.
Demand curves are thus not
stationary. Rather, they shift to the right or left due to a number of causes.
There are changes in tastes, habits, and customs of the consumers; changes in
income expenditure; changes in the prices of substitutes and complements;
expectations about future changes in prices and incomes and changes in the age
and composition of the population, etc.
A
movement along a demand curve takes place when there is a change in the
quantity demanded due to a change in the commodity’s own price. This is
illustrated in Figure 10.6 which shows that when the price is OP1 the quantity demanded is OQ1 with the fall in price, there has been a
downward movement along the same demand curve D1D1from point A to B. This is known as an extension in
demand. On the contrary, if we take В as the original price-demand point, then
a rise in the price from OP2 to OP1 leads to a fall in the quantity demanded from
OQ2 to OQ1. The consumer
moves upwards along the same demand curve D1D1 from point В to A. This is known as the contraction in demand.
The Law of Demand:
The law of demand expresses a
relationship between the quantity demanded and its price. It may be defined in
Marshall’s words as “the amount demanded increases with a fall in price, and
diminishes with a rise in price.” Thus it expresses an inverse relation between
price and demand.
The law refers to the
direction in which quantity demanded changes with a change in price. In the
figure, it is represented by the slope of the demand curve which is normally
negative throughout its length. The inverse price-demand relationship is based
on other things remaining equal. This phrase points toward certain important
assumptions on which this law is based.
It’s Assumptions. These
assumptions are:
(i)
there is no change in the tastes and preferences of the
consumer;
(ii)
the income of the consumer remains constant;
(iii)
there is no change in customs;
(iv)
the commodity to be used should not confer distinction on the
consumer;
(v)
there should not be any substitutes for the commodity;
(vi)
there should not be any change in the prices of other products;
(vii) there should not be any possibility of change
in the price of the product being used;
(viii) there should not be any
change in the quality of the product; and
(ix)
the habits of the consumers should remain unchanged. Given these
conditions, the law of demand operates. If there is change even in one of these
conditions, it will stop operating.
Explain the law with the help
of Table 10.1 and Figure 10.1.
Causes
of Downward Sloping Demand Curve:
Why does a demand curve slope
downward from left to right? The reasons for this also clarify the working of
the law of demand. The following are the main reasons for the downward sloping
demand curve.
(1) The law of demand is
based on the law of Diminishing Marginal Utility. According to this law, when a
consumer buys more units of a commodity, the marginal utility of that commodity
continues to decline. Therefore, the consumer will buy more units of that
commodity only when its price falls. When fewer units are available, the utility
will be high and the consumer will be prepared to pay more for the commodity.
This proves that the demand will be more at a lower price and it will be less
at a higher price. That is why the demand curve is downward sloping.
(2) Every commodity has
certain consumers but when its price falls, new consumers start consuming it,
as a result, demand increases. On the contrary, with the increase in the price
of the product, many consumers will either reduce or stop their consumption and
the demand will be reduced. Thus, due to the price effect when consumers
consume more or less of the commodity, the demand curve slopes downward.
(3) When the price of a
commodity falls, the real income of the consumer increases because he has to
spend less in order to buy the same quantity. On the contrary, with the rise in
the price of the commodity, the real income of the consumer falls. This is
called the income effect. Under the influence of this effect, with the fall in
the price of the commodity, the consumer buys more of it and also spends a
portion of the increased income on buying other commodities. For instance, with
the fall in the price of milk, he will buy more of it but at the same time, he
will increase the demand for other commodities. On the other hand, with the
increase in the price of milk, he will reduce its demand. The income effect of a
change in the price of an ordinary commodity is positive, and the demand curve
slopes downward.
(4) The other effect of
change in the price of the commodity is the substitution effect. With the fall
in the price of a commodity, the prices of its substitutes remain the same, and consumers will buy more of this commodity rather than the substitutes. As a
result, its demand will increase. On the contrary, with the rise in the price
of the commodity (under consideration) its demand will fall, given the prices
of the substitutes. For instance, with the fall in the price of tea, the price
of coffee being unchanged, the demand for tea will rise, and contrariwise, with
the increase in the price of tea, its demand will fall.
(5) There are persons in
different income groups in every society but the majority is in the low-income
group. The downward sloping demand curve depends upon this group. Ordinary
people buy more when the price falls and less when the price rises. The rich do not
have any effect on the demand curve because they are capable of buying the same
quantity even at a higher price.
(6) There are different uses
of certain commodities and services that are responsible for the negative slope
of the demand curve. With the increase in the price of such products, they will
be used only for more important uses and their demand will fall. On the
contrary, with the fall in price, they will be put to various uses and their
demand will rise. For instance, with the increase in the electricity charges,
power will be used primarily for domestic lighting, but if the charges are
reduced, people will use power for cooking, fans, heaters, etc.
Exceptions
to the Law of Demand:
In certain cases, the demand
curve slopes up from left to right, i.e., it has a positive slope. Under
certain circumstances, consumers buy more when the price of a commodity rises,
and less when the price falls, as shown by the D curve in Figure 10.7. Many causes
are attributed to an upward-sloping demand curve.
(i) War:
If a shortage is feared in
anticipation of war, people “may start buying for building stocks or for
hoarding even when the” price rises.
(ii) Depression:
During a depression, the
prices of commodities are very low and the demand for them is also less. This
is because of the lack of purchasing power among consumers.
(iii) Giffen Paradox:
If a commodity happens to be
a necessity of life like wheat and its price goes up, consumers are forced to
curtail the consumption of more expensive foods like meat and fish, and wheat
being still the cheapest, the food they will consume more of it. The Marshallian
example is applicable to developed economies. In the case of an underdeveloped
economy, with the fall in the price of an inferior commodity like maize,
consumers will start consuming more of the superior commodity like wheat. As a
result, the demand for maize will fall. This is what Marshall called the Giffen
Paradox which makes the demand curve have a positive slope.
(iv) Demonstration Effect:
If consumers are affected by
the principle of conspicuous consumption or demonstration effect, they will
like to buy more of those commodities which confer distinction on the
possessor, when their prices rise. On the other hand, with the fall in the
prices of such articles, their demand falls, as is the case with diamonds.
(v) Ignorance Effect:
Consumers buy more at a
higher price under the influence of the “ignorance effect”, where a commodity
may be mistaken for some other commodity, due to deceptive packing, label, etc.
(vi) Speculation:
Marshall mentions speculation
as one of the important exceptions to the downward sloping demand curve.
According to him, the law of demand does not apply to the demand in a campaign
between groups of speculators. When a group unloads a great quantity of a thing
onto the market, the price falls and the other group begins buying it. When it
has raised the price of the thing, it arranges to sell a great deal quietly.
Thus when the price rises, demand also increases.
Income Demand:
We have so far studied price
demand in its various aspects, keeping other things constant. Let us now study
income demand which indicates the relationship between income and the quantity
of a commodity demanded. It relates to the various quantities of a commodity or
service that will be bought by the consumer at various levels of income in a
given period of time, other things being equal. Things that are assumed to
remain equal are the price of the commodity in question, the prices of related
commodities, and the tastes, preferences, and habits of the consumer for it. The
income-demand function for a commodity is written as D – f (y). The
income-demand relationship is usually direct.
The
demand for the commodity increases with the rise in income and decreases with
the fall in income, as shown in Figure 10.8 (A). When income is OI, the quantity
demanded is OQ, and when income rises to OI1 the
quantity demanded also increases to OQ1. The reverse
case can also be shown likewise. Thus, the income demand curve ID has a
positive slope. But this slope is in the case of normal goods.
Let
us take the case of a consumer who is in the habit of consuming an inferior
good. So long as his income remains below a particular level of his minimum
subsistence, he will continue to buy more of this inferior good even when his
income increases by small increments. But when his income starts rising above
that level, he reduces his demand for the inferior good. In Figure 10.8 (B), 01
is the minimum subsistence level of income where he buys the IQ of the commodity.
At this level, this commodity is a normal good for him so he increases
its consumption when his income rises gradually from Ol1 to OI2 and to OI.
As “his income rises above 01, he starts buying less of the commodity. For
instance, at QI3 income level, he buys I3Q3which is less
than his IQ. Thus, in the case of inferior goods, the income demand curve ID is
backward sloping.
Cross Demand:
Let us now take the case of
related goods and how the change in the price of one affects the demand for the
other. This is known as cross demand and is written as D = f (pr).
Related goods are of two
types, substitutes and complementary. In the case of substitute or competitive
goods, a rise in the price of one good A raises the demand for the other good
B, “the price of В remaining the same.
The
opposite holds in the case of a fall in the price of A when the demand for В
falls. Figure 10.9 (A) illustrates it. When the price of good A increases from
OA to CM, the quantity of good В “also increases from OB to OB1. The cross-demand curve CD for substitutes is
positively sloping. For with the rise in the price of A, the consumers will
shift their demand to В since the price of В remains unchanged. It is also
assumed here that the incomes, tastes, preferences, etc. of the consumers do
not change.
In
case the two goods are complementary or jointly demanded, a rise in the price
of one good A will bring a fall in the demand for good B. Conversely, a fall in
the price of A will raise the demand for B. This is illustrated in Figure 10.9
(B) where when the price of A falls from OA, to OA, the demand for В increases
from OB to OB1. The demand curve in the case
of complementary goods is negatively sloping like the ordinary demand curve.
If, however, the two goods
are independent, a change in the price of A will have no effect on the demand for
B. We seldom study the relation between two unrelated goods like wheat and
chairs. Mostly as consumers, we are concerned with the price-demand relation of
substitutes and complementary goods.
Short-Run and Long-Run Demand
Curves:
The distinction may be made
between short-run and long-run demand curves. In the case of perishable
commodities such as vegetables, fruit, milk, etc., the change in quantity
demanded to a change in price occurs quickly. For such commodities, there is a
single demand curve with the usual negative slope.
But in the case of durable
commodities such as gadgets, machines, clothes, and others, a change in price
will not have its ultimate effect on the quantity demanded until the existing
stock of the commodity is adjusted which may take a long time. A short-run
demand curve shows the change in quantity demanded to a change in price, given
the existing stock of the durable commodity and the supplies of its
substitutes. On the other hand, the long-run demand curve shows the change in
quantity demanded to a change in price after all adjustments “have been made in
the long-run.
The
relation between the short-run and long-run demand curves is shown in Figure
10.10. Suppose initially consumers are fully adjusted to OP1 price and OQ1 quantity
demanded with equilibrium at point E1, on the
short-run demand curve D1. Now assume that the price falls to OP. In the short-run, consumers will react along the D1 curve and increase the quantity demanded to OQ1 with equilibrium at point E1 After the lapse of some time when adjustments
are made to the new price OP2, a new
equilibrium will be reached at point E3 with
quantity demanded at OQ1. There will be
now a new short-run demand curve passing through point E1 A further fall in the price to ОР1 would first lead to a short-run equilibrium at
point E4 with OQA quantity
demanded and ultimately to a new equilibrium at point E5 with OQ5 quantity
demanded on the short-run demand curve, D1 A line
passing through the final equilibrium points E1, E3 and E5 at each
price traces out the long-run demand curve DL. The long-run
demand curve Dl is flatter than the
short-run demand curves D1, D2, and D3.
Defects of Utility Analysis or
Demand Theory:
The Marshallian utility
analysis has many defects and weaknesses which are discussed below.
(1)
Utility cannot be measured cardinally:
The entire Marshallian
utility analysis is based on the hypothesis that utility is cardinally measured
in ‘utils’ or units and that utility can be added and subtracted. For instance,
when a consumer takes the first chapati, he gets a utility equivalent to 15
units; from the second and third chapati “10 and 5 units respectively and when
he consumes the fourth chapati marginal utility becomes zero. If it is supposed
that he has no desire after the fourth chapati, the utility from the fifth will
be negative 5 units if he takes this chapati. In this way, the total utility in
each case will be 15, 25, 30, and 30, while from the fifth chapati the total
utility will be 25 (30-5).
Besides, the utility analysis
is based on the assumption that the consumer is aware of his preferences and
is capable of comparing them. For example, if the utility of one apple is 10
units, of a banana 20 units, and of an orange 40 units, it means that the
consumer gives twice the preference to banana as against apple and four times
to orange. It shows that utility is transitive. Hicks opines that the basis of
the utility analysis, that it is measurable, is defective because the utility is a
subjective and psychological concept that cannot be measured cardinally. In
reality, it can be measured ordinally.
(2)
Single Commodity Model is Unrealistic:
The utility analysis is a
single commodity model in which the utility of one commodity is regarded as independent of the other. Marshall considered substitutes and complementaries
as one commodity, but it makes the utility analysis unrealistic. For instance,
tea and coffee are substitute products. When there is a change in the stock of
any one product, there is a change in the marginal utility of both the products.
Suppose there is an increase in the stock of tea. There will not only be a fall in
the marginal utility of tea but also of coffee.
Similarly, a change in the
stock of coffee will bring a change in the marginal utility of both coffee and
tea. The effect of one commodity on the other, and vice versa is called the
cross effect. The utility analysis neglects the cross effects of substitutes,
complementaries, and unrelated goods. This makes the utility analysis
unrealistic. To overcome it, Hicks constructed the two-commodity model in the
indifference curve approach.
(3)
Money is an Imperfect Measure of Utility:
Marshall measured utility in
terms of money, but money is an incorrect and imperfect measure of utility
because the value of money often changes. If there is a fall in the value of
money, the consumer will not be getting the same utility from the homogeneous
units of a commodity at different times. A fall in the value of money is a
natural consequence of rising prices.
Again, if two consumers spend
the same amount of money at a time, they will not be getting equal utilities
because the amount of utility depends upon the intensity of desire of each
consumer for the commodity. For instance, consumer A may be getting more
utility than В by spending the same amount of money, if his “intensity of
desire for the commodity is greater. Thus, money is an imperfect and unreliable
measuring rod of utility.
(4)
Marginal Utility of Money is not constant:
The utility analysis assumes
the marginal utility of money to be constant. Marshall supported this argument
on the plea that a consumer spends only a small portion of his income on a
commodity at a time so that there is an insignificant reduction in the stock of
the remaining amount of money. But the fact is that a consumer does not buy
only one commodity but a number of commodities at a time. In this way, when a
major part of his income is spent on buying commodities, the marginal utility
of the remaining stock of money increases.
For instance, every consumer
spends a major portion of his income in the first week of the month to meet his
domestic requirements. After this, he spends the remaining amount of money
wisely. It implies that the utility of the remaining sum of money has
increased. Thus the assumption that the marginal utility of money remains
constant is away from reality and makes this analysis hypothetical.
(5)
Man is not Rational:
The utility analysis is based
on the assumption that the consumer is rational who prudently buys the
commodity and has the capacity to calculate the dis-utilities and utilities of
different commodities, and buys only those units which give him greater
utility. This assumption is also unrealistic because no consumer compares the
utility and disutility of each unit of a commodity while buying it. Rather,
he buys them under the influence of his desires, tastes, or habits. Moreover, the consumer’s income and prices of commodities also influence his purchases. Thus
the consumer does not buy commodities rationally. This makes the utility
analysis unrealistic and impracticable.
(6)
Utility Analysis does not study the Income Effect, Substitution Effect, and Price
Effect:
The greatest defect in the
utility analysis is that it ignores the study of income effect, substitution
effect, and price effect. The utility analysis does not explain the effect of a
rise or fall in the income of the consumer on the demand for the commodities.
It thus neglects the income effect. Again, when the change in the price of
one commodity there is a relative change the price of the other commodity,
the consumer substitute’s one for the other.
This is the substitution
effect that the utility analysis fails to discuss, being based on one- commodity model. Besides, when the price of one commodity changes, there is a
change in its demand and in the demand for related goods. This is the price
effect which is also ignored by the utility analysis. When say, the price of
good X falls the utility analysis only tells us that its demand will increase.
But it fails to analyze the income and substitution effects of a price fall via
the increase in the real income of the consumer.
(7)
Utility Analysis fails to clarify the Study of Inferior and Giffen Goods:
Marshall’s utility analysis
of demand does not clarify the fact as to why a fall in the prices of inferior
and Giffen goods leads to a decline in their demand. Marshall failed to explain
this paradox because the utility analysis does not discuss the income and
substitution effects of the price effect. This makes the Marshallian law of
demand incomplete.
(8)
The Assumption that the Consumer buys more Units of a Commodity when its Price
falls is Unrealistic:
The utility analysis of
demand is based on the assumption that the consumer buys more units of a
commodity when its price falls. It may be true in the case of food products
like oranges, bananas, apples, etc. but not in the case of durable goods. When,
for example, the price of a bicycle or radio falls, a consumer will not buy two
or three bicycles or radios. It is another thing that a rich man may buy two or
three cars, pairs of shoes and a variety of clothes, etc. But he does so
irrespectively of the fall in their prices because he is rich. The argument,
therefore, does not hold good in the case of an ordinary person.
(9)
This Analysis fails to explain the Demand for Indivisible Goods:
The utility analysis breaks
down in the case of durable consumer goods like scooters, transistors, radios,
etc. because they are indivisible. The consumer buys only one unit of such
commodities at a time so it is neither possible to calculate the marginal
utility of one unit nor can the demand schedule and the demand curve for that
good be drawn. Hence the utility analysis is not applicable to indivisible
goods.
These glaring defects in the
utility analysis led economists like Hicks to explain the demand analysis of
the consumer with the help of the indifference curve approach.
Exam studies telegram group
Exam studies
For daily current affairs
POWERPOINT PRESENTATION (PPT)
MCQ/Quiz/General Knowledge/Current Affairs/ H.P. GK.
Webinar-Workshop-FDP-Seminar 2022
Exam studies | |
For daily current affairs | |
POWERPOINT PRESENTATION (PPT) | |
MCQ/Quiz/General Knowledge/Current Affairs/ H.P. GK. | |
Webinar-Workshop-FDP-Seminar 2022 |
0 Comments